FAIR USE NOTICE

FAIR USE NOTICE

A BEAR MARKET ECONOMICS BLOG

Occupy Economics and the Economy


This site may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not always been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. We are making such material available in an effort to advance understanding of environmental, political, human rights, economic, democracy, scientific, and social justice issues, etc. we believe this constitutes a ‘fair use’ of any such copyrighted material as provided for in section 107 of the US Copyright Law.

In accordance with Title 17 U.S.C. Section 107, the material on this site is distributed without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for research and educational purposes. For more information go to: http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/17/107.shtml

If you wish to use copyrighted material from this site for purposes of your own that go beyond ‘fair use’, you must obtain permission from the copyright owner.

FAIR USE NOTICE FAIR USE NOTICE: This page may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. This website distributes this material without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for scientific, research and educational purposes. We believe this constitutes a fair use of any such copyrighted material as provided for in 17 U.S.C § 107.

Read more at: http://www.etupdates.com/fair-use-notice/#.UpzWQRL3l5M | ET. Updates
FAIR USE NOTICE FAIR USE NOTICE: This page may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. This website distributes this material without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for scientific, research and educational purposes. We believe this constitutes a fair use of any such copyrighted material as provided for in 17 U.S.C § 107.

Read more at: http://www.etupdates.com/fair-use-notice/#.UpzWQRL3l5M | ET. Updates

All Blogs licensed under Creative Commons Attribution 3.0

Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported License.


Wednesday, May 20, 2015

Robert Reich: 10 Ideas to Save the Economy #4: Bust Up Wall Street




Economy

Any bank that's too big to fail is too big, period.


When Americans think of how the economic rules are stacked against them, they naturally think of Wall Street.

When the Wall Street bubble burst in 2008 because of excessive risk-taking, millions of working Americans lost their jobs, health insurance, savings, and homes.

But The Street is back to many of its old tricks. And its lobbyists are busily rolling back the Dodd-Frank Act, intended to prevent another crash.

The biggest Wall Street banks are also much larger. In 1990, the five biggest banks had 10 percent of all of the nation's banking assets. Now, they have 44 percent - more than they had at the time of the 2008 crash.

They have a virtual lock on taking companies public, play key roles pricing commodities, are involved in all major U.S. mergers and acquisitions and many overseas, and responsible for most of the trading in derivatives and other complex financial instruments.

And as they've gained dominance over the financial sector, they've become more politically potent. They're major sources of campaign funds for both Republicans and Democrats.

Wall Street banks supply personnel for key economic posts in Republican and Democratic administrations, and lucrative employment to economic officials when they leave Washington.

It's a vicious cycle. The bigger they get, the more likely it is that government will bail them out if they get into trouble again. This, in turn, confers on them an ever-larger competitive advantage over smaller, community-minded banks that don't have the implied guarantee - which gives the biggest banks even more economic and political power.

What should be done?

First, resurrect the Glass-Steagall Act that used to separate investment from commercial banking.

Second, put a small sales tax on every financial transaction. This would discourage speculation and slow down the casino. Not incidentally, such a tax could generate billions of dollars a year for, say, better schools.

But the most important thing we should do is bust up the big banks. Any bank that's too big to fail is too big, period.

Antitrust law should be used the way it was against the big oil trusts and the telephone monopoly. The idea was to prevent too much economic and political power from concentrating in too few hands. And that's precisely the problem with Wall Street.

The only sure way to stop excessive risk-taking on Wall Street so you don't risk losing your job or your savings or your home, is to put an end to the excessive economic and political power of Wall Street.

It's time to bust up the big banks.

ROBERT B. REICH's film "Inequality for All" is now available on DVD and blu-ray, and on Netflix. Watch the trailer below:




Robert B. Reich has served in three national administrations, most recently as secretary of labor under President Bill Clinton. He also served on President Obama's transition advisory board. His latest book is "Aftershock: The Next Economy and America's Future." His homepage is www.robertreich.org.

Monday, May 18, 2015

Why Capitalism Is Evil


Daily Kos



News, Community, Action

Since Jerome a Paris has reminded us that We're All Plutocrats Now (*irony*), it might be a good time to get some clarity on Capitalism itself.

I was surprised by people's reaction to the conclusion Michael Moore drew in, Capitalism: A Love Story, that Capitalism Is Evil.  I thought people mostly knew that, or at least strongly suspected it, so the idea wouldn't be startling.
Of course capitalists don't think Capitalism is evil.  But many progressives, too, were taken aback by Moore's blunt conclusion -- either disturbed by the potential implications, or, more often, apparently not having thought about it deeply enough to have a clear opinion.

But many more people than just Michael Moore have thought deeply about whether Capitalism is Evil, and the arguments and evidence, when laid out (as I will shortly do), demonstrate that Capitalism is indeed evil, by any reasonable definition "evil."  In other words, Capitalism is not just evil, it is VERY evil -- or, we might say, Capitalism can be proved Evil beyond a reasonable doubt.
[If you're not in the mood for a lengthy proof of Capitalism's evil, or you already knew it was evil, then check out Cassiodorus on Class Divisions, Utopia, or Democracy; Jerome a Paris on the Media's role in all this; veritas curat on the systemic accounting errors that hide Capitalism's evil; or Marcion on an Internationalist approach to global regulation of capital.  But if you think Capitalism might not be evil, I encourage you to read on...]


Capitalism

Moore attempted to reveal Capitalism's dark side by showing how Capitalism systematically causes serious, unnecessary harm, inconsistent with our basic moral commitments.  Perhaps more important, Moore attempted to break the taboo around criticizing Capitalism and to say the words aloud -- "Capitalism Is Evil."

But breaking down the layers of capitalist-apologist propaganda that have accumulated in our brains, and challenging our preconceptions about Capitalism, is no small job.  People's reactions to the movie revealed many of the false meme's lurking in our subconscious, like, "Capitalism may be bad, but the alternatives are worse," and "Capitalism has some negative effects, but the overall benefits of Capitalism would be positive if we protected against its harsher aspects," and "Replacing Capitalism would surely eliminate freedoms, so we might not be better off, and we could be much worse off."

I will confront these memes not with my own arguments, but instead with the much deeper thinking of several subject matter experts: Michael Albert, Joel Kovel, Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, and Michael Moore.

Michael Albert's book, Parecon; Joel Kovel's book, The Enemy of Nature, Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis' book, Capitalism and Democracy, as well as Moore's documentary, Capitalism: A Love Story, thoroughly consider the question of whether Capitalism is Evil, and their combined arguments carry more force than any one argument alone.

Capitalism's Capitalist


Albert approaches Capitalism from the standpoint of economic justice, and argues forcefully that Capitalism's methods and outcomes are intrinsically destructive of people and institutions.  Kovel presses an environmental critique, showing that regardless of the negative social implications (which he nonetheless details impressively), Capitalism necessarily will result in the destruction of our environment, nature generally, and eventually the planet -- so Capitalism is inexorably opposed to humanity, and indeed all life. Bowles and Gintis consider the conditions necessary for Democracy, and the extent to which Capitalism not only undermines the institutions of Democracy, but also makes people less capable of governing themselves.  Finally, Moore approaches the question from an ethic of caring, attempting to illustrate that Capitalism exacts an intolerable and unnecessary toll on people's lives, and is inconsistent with our most basic values.

I will first lay out the four arguments in greater depth, and then consider whether the most popular defenses of Capitalism can survive the heat of these critiques.  We will see that they do not, which in turn begs the question of possible alternatives to Capitalism that might create for us a better world, or at least a sustainable and less-bad world.  That question I will answer, too, but separately, as part of my Economic Power series.


Parecon Small
 
Michael Albert
Parecon: Life After Capitalism


Michael Albert sums it up like this:  
[C]apitalist globalization produces poverty, ill-health, shortened life-spans, reduced quality of life, and ecological collapse...Humanity's well-being does not guide the process, but is instead sacrificed on behalf of private profit.
That's why it's bad.  The cause of this badness, according to Albert, is that:
"Capitalism revolves around private ownership of the means of production, market allocation, and corporate divisions of labor.  It remunerates property, power, and to a limited extent contribution to output.  Class divisions arise from differences in property ownership, and differential access to empowered work versus subservient work.  Class divisions induce huge differences in decision-making influence and quality of life."
Albert argues for an alternate vision, which he calls Participatory Economics (or "Parecon"), that reverses each of these paradigms.  So, for example, instead of private ownership of the means of production, each workplace would be owned in equal part by all citizens.  Top-down hierarchical decision-making structures would be replaced with bottom-up democratic institutions.  Instead of remunerating property, power, and output, Parecon would reward effort and sacrifice.  Instead of creating differential access to empowered work and decision-making influence, people would have balanced job-complexes that allow everyone to engage in some empowering work, and require everyone to engage in some grunt work.

Albert's enterprise is primarily to show why these alternative arrangements are in fact feasible, and could be administered fairly, without making us crazy, and without the frustrating or inefficient bureaucracy that people worry would engulf us if we ever attempted to replace our Dilbert-esque workplaces with something better.

But for the purposes of this essay, we do not need to establish that Albert has a better idea.  Only that Capitalism does in fact necessarily "sacrifice humanity's well-being on behalf of private profit." Albert's arguments toward this conclusion are strong.

Capitalism DOES reliably remunerate property, as any trust-funder knows, but not necessarily hard work, as any good janitor, day laborer knows, or even some school teachers, bus drivers, and airline pilots.

The class awareness around accumulated property is deeply engrained in our consciousness -- children's  stories frequently revolve around the contrasting fates of peasants and kings, princes and paupers. By adulthood, we are accustomed to separate-but-equal accommodations for the wealthy in nearly all public places -- airplanes, sports stadiums, freeways, and airport waiting lounges.  Nearly everywhere in modern society, the wealthy have created for themselves a separate shadow world of superior facilities in education, training, transportation, entertainment, athletics, information, and shopping.  We are even seeing fast-tracks for the wealthy in hospitals and airport security lines.

The end result of these superior accommodations is a self-perpetuating cycle that better prepares the wealthy and their progeny to successfully assume positions of influence and leadership, and thus further expand their wealth.  This cycle, of course, fatally undermines the alleged justification for the wealth disparities in the first place -- that they were somehow "earned" or "deserved," rather than received by inheritance, marriage, or appointment.

But Albert goes further, pointing out that "each of these modes of connecting actors imposes on the economy pressures that subvert solidarity, equity, diversity, and self-management."  In other words, the foundation of a just society is a culture of shared understanding that we are all in this together, that we have to depend on each other, that we have to help each other, and that we have to do these things while respecting our differences and granting each other the right to uniqueness and self-actualization, so that we can truly know freedom.
It's no small task to credibly define such institutions, although Albert may in fact have done it; give him a read.

But it is not hard to see that Capitalism institutionally ensures outcomes that are approximately as devastating as Albert describes, and approximately as devastating as we see in the real world after a few centuries' experiment with Capitalism.  Further, the precise features that define Capitalism -- private ownership of the means of production, hierarchical control of the workplace, remuneration of property and power -- can be pretty clearly shown to lead to class divisions, unequal opportunity, and huge discrepancies in decision-making opportunity and quality of life.

When the benefits of the system are concentrated in a very few, and most people are left dramatically worse off, it is indeed fair to say that humanity's well-being has been sacrificed on behalf of private profit.  And the system that causes it may be called by its true name, "Evil."

But if structural sociological analysis is not your thing, Joel Kovel takes a very different approach.

Joel-Kovel-Enemy-of-Nature
 
Joel Kovel
The Enemy of Nature: The End of Capitalism or the End of the World?

Kovel intends quite literally the harsh dilemma posed by his book's subtitle.  He spends considerable effort showing that our society will either end Capitalism or it will end us -- at least most of us, and life as we know it.

One of Kovel's more intriguing suggestions is that the western environmental movement is misguidedly attempting to reconcile Capitalism and Environmentalism (e.g., Clean Water Act, Emissions Cap-and-Trade) is misguided and cannot succeed.  Some of his best analysis focuses on the way Capitalism tends to shape the behavior of people and institutions, so that disasters like the explosion at Union Carbide's Bhopal chemical plant, which killed 16,000 and injured perhaps 500,000 more, should be understood as inevitable, rather than aberrational.  I recommend the entire book.

But I am going to extract just a piece of Kovel's argument, which directly considers the structural elements of capitalism that (in Kovels's view) ensure that capitalism will destroy the world, and why incremental reforms cannot adequately mitigate this dire outcome.  Obviously if this argument is true, then Michael Albert's notions of social justice hardly need be considered: we either jettison Capitalism, or we die -- or at least most of us and our descendants die.
Kovel focuses on three essential elements of Capitalism:
1. Capitalism tends to degrade the conditions of its own production.
2. Capitalism must expand without end in order to exist
3. Capital leads to a chaotic world-system, increasingly polarized between rich and poor, which cannot adequately address the ecological crisis.
 The combination makes an ever-growing ecological crisis an iron necessity so long as capital rules, no matter what measures are taken to tidy up one corner or another.
Kovel's first point, that Capitalism tends to degrade the conditions of its own production, is intended to apply broadly to the intrinsic destructiveness of Capitalism.  Capitalism cannot function without profit, and so the capitalist firm is pressured to maximize the gap between cost and price.

Because competitive pressures tend to limit price, cost-cutting becomes a paramount concern of capitalists.  In theory, the cost-cutting is focused on efficient production of commodity inputs.  But in practice, the cost-pressure is extended to three non-commodity inputs: public infrastructure, people's labor, and nature itself.

Kovel argues that the pressure to squeeze as much as possible out of people, public infrastructure, and nature, while paying as little as possible, fouls the world by breaking people, disrupting ecosystems, and filling our society with externalized costs, such as pollution.

This degradation may be localized, such as in the Bhopal explosion that resulted from a blizzard of risky cost-cutting measures, or may be generalized, such as the overall global crisis resulting from global warming.  However, Kovel insists, neither scenario should be characterized as industrial accidents because they are inevitable outcomes of a system that generates profit by intentionally imposing hardships and creating risk.

The standard business school rejoinder is that all would be well were capitalist institutions merely required to internalize their costs, and so these tragedies reflect only market distortions, not systemic flaws.  And this brings us to Kovel's second principle: Capitalism Must Expand In Order to Exist.

Any firm that ceases to grow becomes a relatively less attractive investment, and capital is withdrawn and moved to faster growing (i.e., higher returning) firms.  CEOs who cannot increase the rate of profit are removed.  Any firm that fails to grow will simply disappear, its assets purchased by another.  No matter how large Microsoft or Wal-Mart become, their urge to grow further is unabated.
As a result, efforts to internalize costs are consistently defeated by firms clever enough to find a previously unnoticed opportunity to create an externality.  Or if protective regulations have closed one loophole, the unquenchable thirst for profits will result in political action to open a new loophole.

The pressure to do so is extraordinary, because for capital, it is literally a matter of life or death, and that is a defining element of Capitalism.  Although a natural person or a non-profit organization of any size can cover its costs and continue in business indefinitely, the objective of a capitalist organization is not the underlying work, but the extracted profit, so if the profit ceases to grow, capital is moved elsewhere, and the business begins to implode.  To resist this result, capitalist firms will seek to squeeze additional profits, even if it ends up crushing the life out of what otherwise was a well-functioning business.  It happens over and over.

Kovel is particularly critical of proposed capitalist-oriented solutions to the inevitable economic crisis posed by the quest for endless growth.  For example, Kovel argues against the Kyoto carbon-trading scheme:
"Kyoto proceeds on a two-tiered front: to create new markets for trading credits to pollute among the industrial powers, and to create...'Clean Development Mechanisms'...in the South that would offset carbon emissions by building projects, like tree farms, whose goal is the sequestration of carbon.  This immense superstructure...rests on two guiding assumptions: Give the corporate sector and the capitalist state the leading role in containing global warming; and do so by making the control of atmospheric carbon the site of new markets and new nodes of accumulation...
The defects of this mammoth blunder are myriad.  The scheme is inherently incoherent, for it entails innumerable points that simply cannot be measured or compared.  This is essentially because it tries to evade the point of a rational policy, which would be to leave the carbon in the ground in the first place -- in other words, one that would put limits on capital.  In doing so, Kyoto offers opportunities for swindling of all kinds.
Finally, and most revealing, the scheme will fail precisely insofar as it succeeds -- for the money that is to be made as a bribe to get corporate cooperation will of course not be placed in anybody's mattress.  It will enter the great circuits of capital
where it will be used to make more money -- perhaps by building golf courses, or expanding air travel, or going wherever the never-ending and cancerous pressure for growth leads.

In other words, Capitalism cannot be used to defeat itself, and if Capitalism is itself the cause of our most deadly problems, as Kovel demonstrates persuasively, then it will have to be replaced not reformed.

Capitalism and Democracy
 
Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis
Democracy and Capitalism:
Property, Community, and the Contradictions of Modern Social Thought


Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis' Democracy and Capitalism may be perhaps the most thorough analysis of the manner in which Capitalism opposes and even undermines Democracy, but it is a little dense for the non-academic reader.  I will attempt to tease out the basic argument.

Bowles and Gintis conclude that "no capitalist society may be called democratic in the straightforward sense of securing personal liberty and rendering the exercise of power socially accountable."  A true commitment to Democracy, they argue, requires "establishing a democratic social order and eliminating the central institutions of the capitalist economy."

The reason that Capitalism and Democracy are fatally opposed to each other is because Democracy entails the expansion of the rights of people, whereas Capitalism embodies the expansion of the rights of property, and these rights necessarily clash.

Liberal theory considered the state public, and the economy private.  Therefore, the design of the liberal state balances obligations to respect both democratic rights and property rights.  However, because the economy was considered a private sphere, corresponding democratic controls were not devised, and Capitalism was allowed free reign, instead of designing an economic democracy analogous to our political democracy.

Bowles and Gintis argue that this is a fundamental error in the design of our polity, because in fact economic decision-making has as much public impact as political decision-making, but Liberal theory cannot justify the lack of public input or democratic controls in the economy, given its justifications for both public input and democratic controls in the state.

Moreover, "Democracy [not only] promises the collective accountability of power," but it also promises "the ability of people to effectively carry out their individual and common projects unencumbered by arbitrary restraint."
 Capitalism, or, the failure to apply democratic principles to the economy, allows all kinds of domination to occur, including who gets privileged opportunities to win or lose within the economic sphere, as well as significant distortions of democracy in the political sphere.  Or, as Bowles and Gintis put it,
"The rules of chess make it immaterial who plays with white and who with black; the rules of the game that make up society, however, generally confer systematic advantage on one group or another...The asymmetry of the games is the key to our understanding of domination."
But despite their excellent analysis of the specific forms of domination that occur in an undemocratic economy, their final blow is aimed at the nature of the market itself, which Liberal theory mostly understands as a mechanism for the exchange of goods and services.

Bowles and Gintis point out, however, that "exchanges are far more than a simple transfer of ownership.  They are complex social relationships"as illustrated by the kinds of exchanges that occur "between boss and worker, lender and borrower, or between buyers and sellers of different nations."  A market arena of self-interested and anonymous interaction might reduce not only the need for compassion, but also the sentiment itself.  In this respect, the economy produces people as well as things, and the capitalist economy produces people that are not ideally equipped with the democratic sentiments and capacities.

In all these ways (and more, do read the book), Capitalism fatally undermines Democracy, including Democracy's promise of the freedom to carry out our individual and common projects free from arbitrary restraint.  To the extent that Democracy is just and good, Bowles and Gintis conclude, Capitalism is the opposite.

Michael Moore Capitalism Movie Poster
 
Michael Moore
Capitalism: A Love Story

The movie's website claims that all his films revolve around just two questions: Who are we, and why do we behave the way that we do?

In film after film, Moore's answer to the first question is that we are just normal people -- friends, neighbors, people who work hard, people modestly trying to make their way in the world.  When Moore looks at America, he does not see celebrities, politicians, or athletes -- he just sees people.  And each of his movies introduces us to a new cast and their stories.

As for the second question, why do we behave the way that we do, Moore never finds a satisfying answer.  Why do we shut down local economies?  In Roger and Me, he couldn't get an answer.  In Bowling for Columbine, he wondered why do we immerse ourselves in guns, violently endangering ourselves and our children -- especially when other societies seem to successfully limit the prevalence of both guns and violence?

Fahrenheit 911 explored the corruption of our political system, and Sicko of our medical system.  Both films concluded that we had submitted ourselves to regimes that made no sense, at least compared with the alternatives.

Finally, in Capitalism: A Love Story, Moore addressed Capitalism itself, revealing it as the moving force behind corruption of judges, foreclosures, heartless evictions, underpaid-and-overworked airline pilots, and massive, institutionalized theft.  Juxtaposed against this, Moore shows that the basic principles of Capitalism are not consistent with moral and religious codes, and he presented the possibility of worker-owned enterprises as an alternative.

Essentially, Moore asked whether, given the extraordinary weight of evidence that Capitalism is harmful, and the apparent availability of alternatives, why we should tolerate it?  In an interview with Naomi Klein, Moore elaborated his argument:
"Capitalism is the legalization [of] greed.  Greed has been with human beings forever. We have a number of things in our species that you would call the dark side, and greed is one of them. If you don't put certain structures in place or restrictions on those parts of our being that come from that dark place, then it gets out of control. Capitalism does the opposite of that. It not only doesn't really put any structure or restriction on it. It encourages it, it rewards it."
Summary

So from Albert's standpoint, the fundamental principles of Capitalism systematically degrade the conditions of social interaction, thus dividing us from one another, impoverishing us, and eventually sacrificing our collective well-being for the benefit of the few.

For Kovel, Capitalism will inevitably consume all of nature and the ecosystems that we depend on to survive. Thus, if we were to exercise what Thomas Hobbes would have characterized as our right and our duty to survive, then destroying Capitalism before it destroys us is an imperative.

Bowles and Gintis find in Democracy and the self-actualization of people the ultimate objective of our creating a society together, and Capitalism is undermines this fundamental social obligation.

For Moore, Capitalism destroys that which we love, and is opposed to our most basic moral principles.

All conclude, explicitly, that Capitalism is harmful, destructive, unjustified, and must be replaced.  Moore calls it "evil," and the others are similarly unequivocal in their denunciation.

Objections

The objections I cited originally are not as well-developed as the critiques I then attempted to summarize.  Indeed, Michael Moore mentioned in his interview that those taken aback by his conclusion frequently ask, "What's wrong with making money?  Why can't I open a shoe store?"

This objection seems to capture well the common concern -- If Capitalism is Evil, then how can we engage in economic activity?  What is allowed instead?  Is it okay to do honest work and be able to buy things I want in return?
These very practical questions do not express any kind of disagreement with the logic of the arguments I have summarized, nor any disagreement with the underlying premises of the argument.  Compare these additional objections noted at the beginning:
"Capitalism may be bad, but the alternatives are worse," and "Capitalism has some negative effects, but the overall benefits of capitalism would be positive if we only protected against its harsh aspects," and "Replacing capitalism would eliminate freedoms, so we might not be better off, and we could be much worse off."
The focus is consistently on whether better alternatives exist, and do those alternatives have unknown risks, and what is the likelihood that we could successfully transition?

These are fair questions to which we must now turn.  We are lucky to have a rich literature exploring the possibilities, and enough clarity that we could begin to chart our course should we summon the courage to change. These will be the subjects of future essays.

Conclusion

Let us close this topic then, with a clear commitment not to reforming Capitalism or rationalizing Capitalism, or making Capitalism better or kinder, but instead to replacing it, and eliminating it, because the facts and the logic, and the weight of the argument demonstrate, beyond a reasonable doubt, that Capitalism is Evil.

Capitalism Tower Cartoon

(We have actually known this for a long time)
[Cross-Posted at Jay's Right of Assembly Blog]

Originally posted to Just Call Me Jay on Sat Jan 02, 2010 at 02:12 PM PST.


Wednesday, May 13, 2015

37 Ways to Reform the Economy So It’s Not Rigged for the Rich, According to Progressive Economists



Economy

Unlike the presidential candidates, Joseph Stiglitz, Elizabeth Warren and the Roosevelt Institute offer specifics. 

 
 

Photo Credit: AFP

A new report written by scores of progressives economists has laid out an detailed agenda to dismantle, reverse and fix how the laws and policies governing the American economy are rigged to benefit the wealthiest individuals and largest corporoation.

ADVERTISEMENT
The report, “Rewriting The Rules Of The American Economy: An Agenda For Growth and Shared Prosperity,” has just been released by The Roosevelt Institute, where Sen. Elizabeth Warren and New York City Mayor Bill DeBlasio joined its chief economist Joseph Stiglitz at its press conference.

“The American economy no longer works for most Americans… What is causing this dysfunction?” the report opens, then answering that question and making dozens of specific law and policy changes listed below.

“Some point to technological change or globalization,” it said. “Some posit that government has shackled the free enterprise system and hobbled business. Some say that our economy is simply rewarding the risk takers and job creators who have earned the riches coming their way... None of these arguments gets it right.”

“Skyrocketing incomes for the 1 percent and stagnating wages for everyone else are not independent phenomena, but rather two symptoms of an impaired economy that rewards gaming the system more than it does hard work and investment," it states. "The roots of this dysfunction lie deep in the rules and power dynamics that have prioritized corporate power and short-term gains at the expense of long-term innovation and growth. The outcomes shaped by these rules and power dynamics do not make the economy stronger; indeed, many make it weaker.”

What follows are 37 specific laws and policy changes to restore fairness and balance to the economy without undermining American capitalism.

Fix The Financial Sector

1. End “too big to fail” by imposing additional capital surcharges on systemically risky financial institutions and breaking up firms that cannot produce credible living wills.

2. Better regulate the shadow banking sector.

3. Bring greater transparency to all financial markets by requiring all alternative asset managers to publicly disclose holdings, returns, and fee structures.

4. Reduce credit and debit card fees through improved regulation of card providers and enhanced competition.

5. Enforce existing rules with stricter penalties for companies and corporate officials that break the law.

6. Reform Federal Reserve governance to reduce conflicts of interest and institute more open and accountable elections.

Incentize Long-Term Business Growth

7. Restructure CEO pay by closing the performance-pay tax loophole and increasing transparency on the size of compensation packages relative to performance and median worker pay and on the dilution as a result of grants of stock options.

8. Enact a financial transaction tax to reduce short-term trading and encourage more productive long-term investment.

9. Empower long-term stakeholders through the tax code, the use of so-called “loyalty shares,” and greater accountability for managers of retirement funds.

Make Markets Competitive

10. Restore balance to intellectual property rights to encourage innovation and entrepreneurship.

11. Restore balance to global trade agreements by ensuring investor protections are not prioritized above protections on the environment and labor, and increasing transparency in the negotiation process.

12. Provide health care cost controls by allowing government bargaining.

13. Expand a variant of chapter 11 bankruptcy to homeowners and student borrowers.

Rebalance The Tax System

14. Raise the top marginal rate by converting all reductions to tax credits and limiting the use of credits.

15. Raise taxes on capital gains and dividends.

16. Encourage U.S. investment by taxing corporations on global income.

17. Tax undesirable behavior such as short-term trading or polluting and eliminate corporate welfare and other tax expenditures that foster inefficiency and inequality.

Make Full Employement The Goal

18. Reform monetary policy to give higher priority to full employment.

19. Reinvigorate public investment to lay the foundation for long-term economic performance and job growth, including by investing in large-scale infrastructure renovation: a 10-year campaign to make the U.S. a world leader in innovation, manufacturing, and jobs.

20. Invest in large-scale infrastructure renovation with a 10-year campaign to make the U.S. a world infrastructure innovation, manufacturing, and jobs leader.

21. Expand public transportation to promote equal access to jobs and opportunity.

Empower workers

22. Strengthen the right to bargain by easing legal barriers to unionization, imposing stricter penalties on illegal anti-union intimidation tactics, and amending laws to reflect the changing workplace.

23. Have government set the standards by attaching strong pro-worker stipulations to its contracts and development subsidies.

24. Increase funding for enforcement and raise penalties for violating labor standards.

25. Raise the nationwide minimum wage and increase the salary threshold for overtime pay.

Expand Access to Labor Markets and Opportunities For Advancement

26. Reform the criminal justice system to reduce incarceration rates and related financial burdens for the poor.

27. Reform immigration law to provide a pathway to citizenship for undocumented workers.

28. Legislate universal paid sick and family leave.

29. Subsidize child care to benefit children and improve women’s workforce participation.

30. Promote pay equity and eliminate legal obstacles that prevent employees from sharing salary information.

31. Protect women’s access to reproductive health services.

Expand Economic Security And Opportunity

32. Invest in young children through child benefits, early education, and universal pre-K.

33. Increase access to higher education by reforming tuition financing, restoring protections to student loans, and adopting universal income-based repayment.

34. Make health care affordable and universal by opening Medicare to all.

35. Expand access to banking services through a postal savings bank.

36. Create a public option for the supply of mortgages.

37. Expand Social Security with a supplemental public investment program modeled on private Individual Retirement Accounts, and raise the payroll cap to increase revenue.


Steven Rosenfeld covers national political issues for AlterNet, including America's retirement crisis, democracy and voting rights, and campaigns and elections. He is the author of "Count My Vote: A Citizen's Guide to Voting" (AlterNet Books, 2008).

Tuesday, May 5, 2015

Do We Need a Global Tax on Wealth?

VICE NEWS



Do We Need a Global Tax on Wealth?


Opinion & Analysis


Taxes have always been politicized. In modern times, no election passes without each campaign's position on taxes being thoroughly scrutinized. And with economic inequality now at the heart of so much political debate, taxes have become an even more polarizing subject.

This is due in no small part to French economist Thomas Piketty's best-selling book, Capital in the Twenty-First Century. After analyzing an unprecedented collection of historical data on income and wealth in Europe and North America dating back to the 18th century, Piketty argued that a global wealth tax is needed in order to save democracy from the rich.

Piketty's conclusion is stark. The concentration of wealth in developed, capitalist economies is creating a world in which the richest sliver of society earns more from what they own — inheritance, property — than from what anyone else can earn from work. Thus, according to Piketty's oft-cited "Second Law of Capitalism," there is an ever-increasing concentration of wealth in fewer and fewer hands.

In such a world, according to Piketty, "nation-states… find that they are too small to impose and enforce rules on [this new] globalized patrimonial capitalism."

The only way out, he argues, is a set of globally coordinated taxes on wealth — 80 percent on income over $500,000 a year, and 50 percent to 60 percent on income over $200,000 a year. The ultimate purpose would neither be to raise government revenue nor to eliminate inequality through traditional redistribution, but to penalize the existence of "excessive" wealth itself and prevent it from occurring in the first place.

Last year, Paul Krugman called Piketty's work "the most important economics book of the year — maybe the decade." Lawrence Summers, who questioned Piketty's findings, nonetheless called the book "a Nobel Prize worthy contribution" to the inequality debate. Given the imposing scale of Piketty's data set, the number of credible challenges to his analysis and findings have so far been few and far between, and have generally been brushed aside by the author.

Which makes it all the more noteworthy that the most serious challenge to Piketty's interpretation of his data came last month from 26-year-old MIT graduate student Matthew Rognlie.

What's the disagreement about? Let's suppose you're a 19th century capitalist during the Industrial Revolution. Your "capital" in this example consists of some land, a couple of factories, and various industrial machines. You rake in a consistent and hefty income for two reasons. First, you find it relatively easy to replace the humans who work on your land and in your factories with more machines — in other words, more capital — and therefore keep more of the profits for yourself. Second, the machines have relatively long productive lives, so you need re-invest only a small proportion of the money they earn you on fixing and replacing them.

However, standard neoclassical economics says that over time, you can't just keep adding more capital to the mix and expect your income to grow at the same rate. There comes a point when that extra tractor or milling machine doesn't add as much value to your operation as the first couple of machines did. It becomes harder and harder to replace people with machines.

Spread over the whole economy, that means opportunities for investing in capital will tend to slow down over time. Eventually, labor — albeit more skilled and therefore more highly paid labor — becomes important again. This is the reason why we're not all still serfs, and why capitalism has raised countless millions out of poverty since the Industrial Revolution, and continues to do so.

Piketty, however, suggests that in modern high-tech economies, the rules have changed. He says the ability to replace labor with capital will remain high and diminish much more slowly than standard economic theory would suggest. This will cause income earned from owning capital to grow faster than income from doing work. The future will start to look like the past.

Rognlie disagrees, and uses software as an example. Although a piece of efficiency-boosting software today might generate a large bundle of cash for the company that uses it, its productive life is much shorter than, say, a cotton gin's was in the 19th century. Software has to be replaced more frequently by highly paid software engineers — who are not easily replaced by machines, hence their high salaries. The profit enjoyed by a business owner after he pays software geeks for the latest version of the software — in other words, for a rapidly depreciating chunk of capital — is therefore relatively smaller than his 19th century counterpart, whose machines were cheaper to maintain, and whose workers were more easily replaced by machines.

Rognlie then deconstructs Piketty's data to examine what's behind the resurgent capital returns that seem to be ushering in a new gilded age. Providing something of an anticlimax to Piketty's epic story, Rognlie finds that this can mostly be explained by increasing house prices. The return to non-housing capital actually ends up looking fairly flat during the period in which Piketty sees the resurgence of gilded age wealth patterns.

Rognlie's findings would suggest very different policy responses than those espoused by Piketty. Rather than pursuing global taxes on wealth, authorities might start more locally by looking at the factors that inflate house prices. For example, regulations on planning and land use — generated and maintained by residents solely out of self interest — that inhibit house building. Or a lack of regional and national transport infrastructure that could ease the pressure on urban house prices by allowing people to live farther outside of major cities while affordably commuting in to work.

Equally as striking as Piketty's work was the public reaction to it. Coming on the heels of the 2008 financial crisis and the ensuing Occupy movement, Piketty's book has been held up as an incontrovertible truth, without differentiation between his remarkable historical work and his more questionable interpretations and policy recommendations. Piketty's supporters seemingly consider the international economic and political centralization that would be necessary to police a huge global tax system to be less threatening to democracy than the rich people it would regulate. This is extremely naive — especially when one considers that it's the capture of government and public institutions by special interests that make concentrated private wealth such a problem for democracy in the first place.

Rather than just taxing the outcomes of the political, social, and economic dynamics that generate today's inequality, we need to look at the dynamics themselves, many of which are underpinned by government. Perhaps the greatest lesson of Rognlie's rebuttal is that the last thing the world needs in such a polarized climate is the idea that there exist sure-fire, programmable solutions to issues as complex as economic inequality.

Follow Alaa al-Ameri on Twitter: @AlaaAmeris

Photo via Flickr